Contemporary Issues

Innovation and Data Privacy: Merger Review in Digital Markets: Part I

[By Tawishi Beria]  The author is a student at the Jindal Global Law School.  Part I Introduction The rapid rise of digital activity across the globe, bringing with it a growth in the might of a select few companies in such digital markets, has raised several concerns, including antitrust and privacy-related issues. In light of the nature of digital markets, characterised by very strong network effects, use of big data, continuous innovation, the existence of barriers to expansion and entry and so on, regulation of any activity that seeks to augment the market power of these digital companies becomes necessary. Ex-ante regulation of digital markets has been suggested by some scholars as a way to face the challenges arising. Considering this, looking at how reviewing mergers and acquisitions (‘M&A’) warrants a change in terms of digital companies becomes pertinent, given that M&A is a tool that already entails ex-ante assessment on part of the competition authorities. BigTechs have been observed as being ‘remarkably active in M&As’ for various purposes. Even though M&A transactions are generally seen as entailing softer antitrust scrutiny, certain factors are analysed by competition authorities looking at the counterfactual. Deals involving digital companies, two factors that become important are innovation and data protection and privacy. Through this article, the author seeks to assess the interplay of conflict between these factors and understand the need for balance and where it lies. This is the first part of a two-part piece. In Part, I, the need for considering innovation and data privacy as factors during merger review in digital markets is assessed independently. This part further looks at the interplay and conflict between the two factors in terms of actual and hypothetical scenarios. Part II analyses two deals involving Facebook and concludes by highlighting the need for changes in enforcement. Considering the factors independently Competition authorities across the world use various determinants to assess the possible pro-competitive and anti-competitive effects of an M&A deal on consumers. Some factors can clearly be demarcated into these categories. However, the two factors that are the subject of this paper-innovation, and privacy, do not strictly classify as either inherently pro-competitive or anticompetitive and can take both forms on a case-to-case basis. In this part, the author briefly argues for considering these factors in merger review, given the debate. 1.     Innovation Although innovation has always been considered as a factor alongside traditional factors like price, quantity, consumer choice, and quality in merger assessment, it has recently gained more attention. Notably, evidence from digital markets on this front is still almost non-existent. However, killer acquisitions in digital markets are very common, requiring consideration of the innovation parameter. When entities with diverse products/services merge, the portfolio effect also comes into play, facilitating increased range, bundling, leveraging, and ultimately deterring innovation. In markets like digital markets, firms can safely be assumed to compete in ‘innovation spaces’ in addition to the relevant product market, mandating analysis. Even though not related to digital markets, the Dow/DuPont merger laid the ground for and provides valuable insights into the innovation theory of harm in M&A deals. In that case, the concern was that ongoing parallel innovation efforts would be disincentivised due to the merger of horizontal competitors. Likewise, the concern in digital markets is that of continued investment in innovation by merged entities. Further, in the case of digital companies, when data, especially in large amounts, comes into the equation, the focus shifts to an interest in data from one previously purely in innovation. Therefore, keeping a check to ensure innovation is necessary. 2.     Data Privacy The consideration of privacy concerns arising from an M&A deal has been debated, since it is argued by some that privacy is not a competition law-related factor, warranting no consideration. However, in digital markets where M&A activity is largely data-driven, the protection of this data and privacy is required. In terms of ensuring consumer welfare, the vulnerability of consumers has to especially be considered in countries like India where consumer protection laws are relatively insufficient and data protection laws are not in place yet. Even in other countries, data protection laws cannot block M&A deals and digital companies do attempt to comply with such laws; accordingly, the author believes that considering the privacy factor reflects the best approach. Given the merged entity’s larger user base, the potential competitive advantages that can be gained by accessing and using big data are relevant. Over the last few years in some data-driven markets, Big Techs have increased their market share, instead of being disrupted by new and innovative services. An increased market share (a direct consequence of any M&A activity) also means an increased volume of data rich in variety and value, along with an enhanced velocity of generation and processing of such data. Coupled with other characteristics of digital markets like network effects and barriers to entry and expansion, it becomes extremely essential to keep a check on the activities of entities that have such data at their disposal. Looking for the Balance Having set out the need to consider these factors, the author now seeks to assess the required balance. The possible interface between the two in certain approved deals and hypothetical situations is elaborated on, addressing questions like what if a particular deal adds to innovation but jeopardises privacy or what if a deal might result in excessive market power but increases innovation and enhances data protection, or how to determine the weight given to these factors. Looking at these factors in actual cases shows the non-consideration of privacy concerns in approving deals. In Microsoft/Yahoo Search! for instance, Yahoo’s continued incentive to innovate as well as Microsoft’s potential ability to make innovation for alternative intelligent solutions difficult was considered, but privacy was not. Google/DoubeClick is another deal that reflects complete disregard of data privacy (particularly in terms of targeted advertising) by the Commission. This is because, on assessment, the authorities found the data collected by DoubleClick to be relatively narrow in scope, whereas the

Innovation and Data Privacy: Merger Review in Digital Markets: Part I Read More »

Amazon & Flipkart v. CCI: Validity of CCI’s order under Section 26(1) of the Competition Act, 2002

[By Ishu Gupta]  The author is a student at Symbiosis Law School, Noida.  Recently, the Karnataka High Court (‘HC’) pronounced its judgement in Amazon Seller Services Pvt. Ltd. & Anr. v. CCI and Ors. (‘Amazon/Flipkart v. CCI’), a writ petition filed under Articles 226 and 227 of the Constitution of India, 1950 seeking to set aside an order of the CCI under Section 26(1), Competition Act, 2002 (‘CA’02’) against Amazon and Flipkart. Amazon/Flipkart v. CCI involved the questions of 1) non-application of mind by the CCI for its prima facie satisfaction under Section 26(1); 2) the order of the CCI being ultra vires the objects and purposes of the CA’02; 3) bar on the CCI’s jurisdiction on account of a pending investigation by the Enforcement Directorate (‘ED’) under Foreign Exchange Management Act, 1993 (‘FEMA’). In this post, the author shall be discussing the judgement of the Karnataka HC in Amazon/Flipkart v. CCI while gazing at the requirement of prima facie satisfaction under Section 26(1) of the CA’02. Further, the challenge to the CCI’s jurisdiction to order an investigation under Section 26(1) of the CA’02 shall be discussed. Finally, the author maps out a three-fold test for satisfying the prima facie case requirement and the jurisdiction issue to edict an investigation under Section 26(1) of the CA’02. Factual Background- Delhi Vyapar Mahasangh (‘informant’) had filed an information with the CCI under Section 19(1) of the CA’02 alleging the violation of Section 3(4) read with Section 3(1) and Section 4 of the CA’02 by Amazon and Flipkart, owing to the existence of preferred sellers and preferential listing on the online market places of Amazon and Flipkart. Given the information supplied by the informant and having regard to the provisions of the CA’02, the CCI passed an order under Section 26(1), thereby instructing the DG to investigate the contravention of Section 3(4) read with Section 3(1) of the CA’02 and not under Section 4, since the CA’02 does not envisage an investigation in cases of collective dominance. The order of the CCI was thereafter challenged before the Karnataka HC in two writ petitions filed by Amazon and Flipkart, separately. The Karnataka HC, while disposing off the writ petitions of Amazon and Flipkart by a common judgement, refused to quash the order of the CCI. Decision- Based on the arguments of the petitioners, the Karnataka HC framed the following questions: What is the nature of the order of the CCI under Section 26 of the CA’02? Whether a prior notice and opportunity of hearing are mandatory at the stage of issuing direction to the DG to hold an inquiry under Section 26(1) of the CA’02? Whether the order of the CCI calls for interference? In respect of questions (a) and (b), the HC decided that an order under Section 26(1) of the CA’02 is an administrative order and is not a part of the adjudicatory process. Additionally, Section 26(1) of the CA’02 does not prescribe the CCI to issue any notice to any party at the time of forming prima facie opinion. Hence, there is no requirement of serving a notice on the opposite parties. While answering question (c), the Karnataka HC relied on Competition Commission of India v. Steel Authority of India Ltd. and Ors. (‘CCI v. SAIL’) and held that the order of the CCI does not call for interference and as such the requirement of giving a reasoned order has been fulfilled by the CCI. Analysis- Prima facie satisfaction of the CCI- In Amazon/Flipkart v. CCI, it was argued by the petitioners that there was no application of mind by the CCI as the CCI had not opined on appreciable adverse effect on competition (‘AAEC’) in its order. Accordingly, the prima facie case requirement under Section 26(1) was not satisfied. In various decisions of the SC and different HCs, it has been held that the CCI’s order under Section 26(1) of the CA’02 is an administrative direction to one of its own administrative wings. It is only a direction simpliciter to investigate and does not form part of the adjudicatory process. The said position is well cemented by the landmark judgements of the SCI in CCI V. SAIL and Excel Corp Care Ltd. v. CCI& Ors. Accordingly, there is no requirement to issue a notice to the opposite party or strict compliance with the principles of natural justice while ordering an investigation under Section 26(1). The sole prerequisite for an investigation order Section 26(1) is the application of mind by the CCI in determining where the facts at hand transmit any contraventions of the provisions under Sections 3 and 4 of the CA’02. Whilst it’s true that for a contravention of Section 3(4) there must be an AAEC, which has to be proven by a market analysis based on the factors given under Section 19(3), it is incorrect to surmise that the CCI has to supply detailed reasons for its decision under Section 26(1) owing to the fact that the same can only happen after an investigation by the DG. Hence, the Karnataka HC was correct in holding that the order of the CCI does not entail an interference as the CCI had looked into the information and applied its mind in deciding the existence of a prima facie case. Jurisdictional challenge against an order under Section 26(1)- The petitioners had argued that the jurisdiction of the CCI was barred because of a pending investigation by the ED under FEMA. It is to be noted that Section 60 of the CA’02 provides for an overriding effect of the CA’02 over any other law in India. Furthermore, the provisions of CA’02 are in addition to and not in derogation of the provisions of other laws, according to Section 62. The Supreme Court of India (‘SC’) has conclusively decided on the issue of the ouster of the CCI’s jurisdiction in presence of sectoral regulators in CCI v. Bharti Airtel Ltd. & Ors. The SC had held that whilst the jurisdiction of the

Amazon & Flipkart v. CCI: Validity of CCI’s order under Section 26(1) of the Competition Act, 2002 Read More »

Facebook’s Antitrust Misadventures: Finale In Sight?

[By Pragya Jain & Akshita Singh]  Pragya is a student at Hidayatullah National Law University, Raipur and Akshita is a student at National Law University Odisha, Cuttack General Overview Facebook’s iconic Senate hearing in 2018, while the punchline of many jokes for years to come, brought a fact into vivid perspective. The CEO, Mr. Zuckerberg, when prompted to provide the most accurate description of Facebook’s business, quipped simply – “Senator, we run ads.” The rebuttal, though seemingly precise, is akin to Pandora’s box of essential legal questions – one of which, concerning dubious anti-competitive practices, is central to this article. This description of Facebook’s services cements a glaring fact: if the service being consumed is free, the consumer is but a misnomer. It can be fairly said that while availing a seemingly “free” service, it is the consumer’s attention that becomes the product. This is the guiding principle behind zero-price markets which are more relevant than ever in the rapidly digitising world. One of the waves brought in by digitization which seems to have patently hit the shores of BigTech is online advertising. Statistics reveal a significant share of 46% of Facebook’s income is on account of online advertising. In fact, a pointed look at the revenue models of BigTech reveals that online advertising is strategically employed by these companies, not only to generate soaring revenues but also to gain dominance in the relevant market. This inevitably puts competition regulators in a spot while demarcating the competitive boundaries for an enterprise in an arena as exponentially advancing and fragile as online advertising. Consequently, the growing dissatisfaction of competition regulators across the globe with BigTech can be evidenced by the onslaught of probes into their practices. Recently, the European Union and Britain commenced twin antitrust proceedings against Facebook. Both the proceedings have been initiated with the intention of deciphering Facebook’s conduct particularly in the online advertising segment. The Commission seeks to undertake a thorough examination of Facebook’s status in the online advertising and social networking markets and whether it’s behaviour has been antithetical to fair competitive practices.. This brings us to the primary objective of the blog which is to discuss the contested knots of the ongoing proceedings against Facebook by the EU and UK and understand the arguments put forth by the Competition regulators. The authors also intend to unravel the future course of action which may be taken by countries, especially India, as their competition regime matures. Facebook’s March to Trial A Peep into Facebook’s Ad-Revenue Model To understand the peculiar problems in the realm of online advertising services, we must first examine the stakeholders in such a scenario. As per the authors, the stakeholders are the advertisers and the consumers of such product offerings. Any platform that hosts such users acts as both the middleman and the agent tasked with enriching the user experience of the consumer. The platform thus, accumulates invaluable information and consumer attention that is further monetised. The advertisers, ranging from small firms to large conglomerates compete for  consumer attention; and as such, the value that they derive from such platforms is immeasurable; both in terms of their market presence as well as innovation. Towards the user, the platform customizes their experience by displaying personalised advertisements that allow them to peruse different product offerings and maximize the value obtained in consideration of their attention and money. The next key concept to understand in this regard is Facebook’s method of ad-auctions, a process wherein Facebook assumes the role of an agent of the user. Essentially, the auction is characterized by generation of a ‘total bid’ which denotes the approximate value that an ad being hypothetically displayed to a user can create. As the final determiner, the ads with the highest estimate of the total bid are displayed to the particular user. The key inputs taken from the advertisers in this process are their bid (the amount they are willing to pay for their desired outcome) and their target audience. These serve to create the relevant market for the advertisers where their ad relevance is determined on the basis of estimated action rates and quality. At this juncture it is key to remember that the relevance of an ad is of the utmost importance and consequently rewarded. Per Facebook’s policy, it may choose to subsidize relevant ads and reduce their costs while the advertisers get good results from the same. It is thus, practicable that in an auction, a relevant ad has a higher chance of winning against a higher bid. Rising Dissatisfaction  Facebook’s use of data over the past few years has raised eyebrows all over. Recently, its use of data collected from advertisers through its online advertising service has struck the eye of the competition regulators in the UK and EU. A probe has been launched to ascertain the potential abuse of data through its classifieds service- Facebook Marketplace. To explain briefly, Facebook Marketplace is an online platform which allows its users to sell and buy goods from one another. The potential breach in competition is in regard to Facebook’s use of commercially valuable data mined from its advertising service to get a leg up for its marketplace. In addition, the UK also geared up to put Facebook’s use of data from its single sign-on authentication service under the microscope, and its recently launched product – Facebook Dating, a service available only in select countries. Facebook Dating is being scrutinised for synthesizing data based on user preferences, groups and events attended as well as mutual friends to recommend potential matches. It also allows the use of other Facebook services such as Messenger and Instagram as add-ons to the Dating profile. Recently these dubious practices have come under fire with the European Commission (EC) and the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) of the UK, for their alleged anti-competitive nature. A peep into the viewpoints of the two competition authorities can be traced on the following lines. To begin with, the investigation initiated by the EC

Facebook’s Antitrust Misadventures: Finale In Sight? Read More »

The Arbitrability Of Antitrust Related Issues And The Competition Act, 2002

[By Aniket Panchal & Mehar Kaur Arora] The authors are students at the Gujarat National Law University.  Introduction: setting the tone The arbitrability of competition law disputes has always been a hot potato. In this regard, arbitrability can be defined as ‘the ability of a dispute to constitute the subject matter of the arbitration.[i] That said, there is no denying the fact that the Competition Law and Arbitration lie at two opposite poles since arbitration is a consensual mode of private dispute resolution, unlike the competition law which seeks to set the seal on fair competition in the market and promote public interest as a whole.  Although it may seem that both the subjects are diametrically opposite to each other, greater heights could be reached if a middle ground is struck by the Competition Law regime in India. With the lack of alternative to the Competition Act 2002 (hereinafter, “the Act”) rather than approaching the domestic courts and the limited powers vested in the Competition Commission of India (hereinafter, “CCI”), there is a pressing need for the door to be opened towards arbitration of certain anti-competitive conducts by dominant entities. In this article, the authors will venture into this not-so-explored terrain. In doing so, the authors will also make a mention of other countries with robust competition law regimes such as the United States and the European Union and their approach towards the same. A sneak peek into the approach adopted by the United States and European Union Last year, in the United States, arbitration was employed over a competition law dispute. In a historic win, the US Department of Justice Antitrust Division (hereinafter, “DOJ”) got a favourable order over a  product market definition in a matter involving the merger of Aluminum firms, namely Aleris and Novelis. While Aleris and Novelis contended that the relevant product market should be broader so as to include sheet ABS (hereinafter, “ABS”) as well, the DOJ maintained that the relevant product market should be restricted only to aluminium ABS.  In this case, it was alleged that the acquisition, if effectuated, would combine two out of four North American producers of aluminium ABS which would lead to sky-scraping concentration (as much as 60%) of total production capacity in the hands of Novelis. After a ten-day-long arbitration, the arbitrator issued a ruling in favour of the US Antitrust Division and found that aluminium ABS constitutes a relevant product market. Interestingly, it is also the first time the antitrust division used its authority to resolve a competition law related matter under the Administrative Dispute Resolution Act (1996). In fact, the Department of Justice marvelled at this development as a “flexible and efficient” arbitration mechanism. In this case, the proposed acquisition of Aleris by Novelis was challenged by the DOJ. Following this ruling, realizing the potential of arbitration in effectively resolving competition law disputes, Attorney General Delharim marvelled “this first-of-its-kind arbitration proved to be an effective procedure for the streamlined adjudication of a dispositive issue in a merger challenge. As demonstrated in this case, arbitration has the potential to be a powerful dispute resolution tool in the right circumstances …”. As for the European Union, there is a ballooning consensus on the full arbitrability of competition law disputes arising out of Article 101 and 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (hereinafter, “TFEU”). However, all the competition law matters which are made arbitrable, are subject to judicial review. While the arbitrability of these disputes arising out of these articles may not require much deliberation, there is a divided opinion on the issues arising out of other provisions such as Articles 106-108 as well as a matter arising under secondary legislation (For instance, the EU Merger Control Regulation).[ii] With regards to the approach adopted by the European Union, it is observable that the position of the United States is somewhat different than that of the EU. This is primarily attributable to the relationship between European Courts or Tribunals and European Competition Law for merger enforcement. To contextualize the same, in the United States a tribunal is always involved in the enforcement of Antitrust, whereas in the EU the competition commission can neither refer antitrust cases to enforcement bodies nor an arbitral tribunal. In a way, the inability of referring antitrust cases to an arbitral tribunal is in line with the objectives of the EU which is entirely opposed to referring cases to enforcement bodies. Is India averse to the confluence of arbitration and competition law? The Indian jurisprudence has taken shape miles away from the approaches adopted by these countries having robust competition law regimes. For starters, the Act that governs India’s competitive landscape has an overriding effect on the other statutes (Section 60), thereby imposing a bar on the jurisdiction of the civil court for adjudication of disputes that are to be dealt with by the CCI (Section 61). Therefore, an alternative mechanism for adjudication of competition disputes has not been prescribed under the Act. In India, the arbitrability of competition law disputes was addressed in the case of Union of India v. Competition Commission of India for the first time in 2012. The Ministry of Railways (Opposite Party) argument was that the mere existence of an arbitration agreement between the parties precludes the CCI from interfering, rendering the case non-maintainable. However, rejecting this argument, the Delhi High Court categorically stated that all disputes brought before the CCI were distinct from contractual duties dealt with by an arbitral tribunal, and the Act, 2002 supersedes all other legislation. It is so since the arbitration tribunals may tend to overlook the nitty-gritty involved in the process of adjudication of disputes of abuse of dominance since it lacks the expertise, mandate and ability to conduct an investigation. Concretizing the ratio, the Bombay High Court, in the case of Central warehousing corporation v. Frontpint Automotive Pvt. Ltd observed that Section 5 of the Arbitration and Conciliation Act is not to be read in isolation of Section 2(3) of

The Arbitrability Of Antitrust Related Issues And The Competition Act, 2002 Read More »

Pre-Packaged Insolvency: A Maiden Affair to Rescue the MSME

[By Neil Kothari and Nidhi Agarwal] Neil is a student at Government Law College, Mumbai and Nidhi is a student at Rizvi Law College, Mumbai. INTRODUCTION On 04th April 2021, an ordinance[i] was passed by the Government whereby a separate chapter, Chapter IIIA, was inserted in the Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016 (“The Code”) dealing with pre-packaged insolvency resolution process. Due to the outbreak of the Covid-19 pandemic, India faced huge economic challenges, and various corporations and individuals were on the brink of insolvency.   As a result, an Ordinance was introduced for insolvency resolution of Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises (“MSME”) in a value maximising and cost-effective manner, by the Government. The Code recognizes this as an “out-of-court” mechanism, wherein the stakeholders benefit from the amalgamation of informal workouts with the legal validity of formal insolvency proceedings. Moreover, appropriate safeguards are also provided for all stakeholders. This process involves a ‘debtor-in-possession with creditor-in-control’ model, whereby the assets of the company would still be under the management of the debtor with the approval taken of the creditors.  This scheme further envisions a shorter timeframe for completing the proceedings. PRE-PACKAGED INSOLVENCY RESOLUTION PROCESS Ever since the introduction of the “Pre-Packaged Insolvency Resolution Process” (“PPIRP”), MSMEs found it difficult to undertake restructuring under the standard Corporate Insolvency Resolution Process (“CIRP”). Since promoters ran these companies, it was impossible for them to resurrect under the current insolvency resolution mechanism whereby the current administration of the company would be removed, and the promoters would not be allowed to participate. Therefore, the latest amendment prescribes a scheme where the Corporate Debtor (“CD”) would be entitled to negotiate with the creditors to stay in business and keep the operations as a going concern. Any corporate debtor classified as MSME would be qualified to initiate a pre-pack process under Section 29A of the Code if the default on its loans is a minimum of Rs.10 lakhs. Such a process requires certain conditions to be fulfilled, To convene a meeting of unrelated financial creditors and seek approval for the appointment of an insolvency professional. A majority vote of 66% of its unrelated financial creditors is required to seek approval for initiation of the process. Also, the members of the corporate debtor are needed to pass a special resolution to approve the initiation of the process.[ii] When all the pre-commencement requirements are fulfilled, the applicant of the corporate debtor may apply to the Adjudicatory Authority (“AA”), filled with the period stated in the abovementioned declaration. In addition to the application, a report of the appointment of an insolvency professional has to be attached, along with a declaration regarding the antecedent transaction under Chapter III or VI of Part II of the Code. The AA is obligated to approve the application if it is complete within fourteen days from the date of filing of the application. When such an application is admitted, the AA declares a moratorium under section 14(1)& (3) of the Code officially appoints the insolvency professional and issues a public notice to the creditors, information utilities, etc. According to the law, the pre-pack process is stipulated to be completed within 120 days from the date of admission. The first 90 days are required to seek approval of the resolution plan from the committee of creditors (“CoC”) and the remaining 30 days for the adjudication by the AA. The insolvency professional under the Code within 90 days can apply for termination of this process if CoC fails to ratify any resolution plan. INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVE The concept of PPIRP was brought into India after its successful demonstration and application globally. United States has two types of PPIRP process; one requires creditors’ approval, and the other one can be initiated solely by the CD. Furthermore, the district courts themselves are responsible for acting as a bankruptcy court where the matter shall be referred to judges dealing specifically with bankruptcy cases. In the United Kingdom, a very popular notion known as ‘Phoenixing’ is used, where the promoters of the insolvent company are allowed to bid for the insolvent business without carrying over its debts. The Government, however, has taken some recommendations from the Graham Committee[iii] to improve the transparency of the PPIRP. CHALLENGES AHEAD  The Pre-Packaged Insolvency Resolution Process had been introduced with benefits arising right from less time taken to complete the proceedings, and low transaction cost being incurred to a continuation of corporate debtor’s business proceedings., etc. However, it still has to face certain challenges during its implementation Approval of the plan by the Committee of Creditors (CoC) The Base Resolution plan proposed by CD needs to be presented to the CoC first. The plan has to be approved by 66% of financial creditors by value. Even though Sec29A allows the CD to apply for PPIRP with the exception of clauses (c) & (h)[iv], but if the financial situation of the CD is stressed or if the account of CD is Non-performing Assets, the creditors will be reluctant to approve the proposed plan. Additionally, unsecured creditors might not be much benefitted from PPIRP as the restructuring plan will favour secured creditors better.   Therefore, the resolution plan proposed by the corporate debtor before the committee of creditors will only delay the process of PPIRP to put the entity back on track. However, with at least 66% vote of CoC, the creditors can transfer the management of the CD to the IP, i.e., from Debtor in Possession Model to Creditor in Possession Model. The IP will then submit an application to the Adjudicating Authority for approval of the application. Initiation of CIRP by Operational Creditors If the OC’s are not content with the Base Resolution Plan or have to reconcile in terms like payment delay, reduced interest rate, etc., they may apply for Section 9. In that case, if the PPIRP is not submitted within the framework of 14 days after filing of CIRP by OC, then the CIRP application shall be given preference over the PPIRP application. This will only

Pre-Packaged Insolvency: A Maiden Affair to Rescue the MSME Read More »

Priority in Enforcement of Security Interest by a Secured Creditor

[By Arya Mittal & Naman Keswani] The authors are students at the Hidayatullah National Law University.  Recently, the Hon’ble Supreme Court of India gave its judgement in the case of India Resurgence Arc Private Limited v. M/s Amit Metaliks Limited & Anr. wherein it held that a dissenting secured financial creditor cannot claim a priority over other creditors based on the security interest held by it. The legal provision in question was Section 30(4) of the Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code, 2016 [“the Code”] which was amended in 2019. The current post seeks to analyse the case in light of the provisions of the Code with regards to the priority of the share of a secured creditor. Facts of the Case India Resurgence Arc Private Limited (“India Resurgence Arc”) is the assignee of rights, title, and interest of Religare Finvest Limited, a secured creditor of the corporate debtor VSP Udyog Private Limited. The resolution plan for the corporate debtor was approved by 95.35% of the creditors, with India Resurgence Arc holding its dissenting opinion. It was of the view that it only received one-sixth of the amount of security interest held by it and it would be more beneficial if the corporate debtor was liquidated since, in that case, it could have enforced its security. The resolution plan was approved by the National Company Law Tribunal, Kolkata and it held the resolution plan to be compliant with all legal requirements provided in the Code. However, India Resurgence Arc appealed to the National Company Law Appellate Tribunal (“NCLAT”) under Section 61(3) of the Code, contending that the approved plan contravened the provisions of the Code but the Appellate Authority dismissed the appeal. Hence, an appeal was preferred before the Supreme Court under Section 62 of the Code. Critical Analysis Priority-based on Security Interest The main contention of India Resurgence Arc was based on the amendment to sub-section 4 of Section 30 of the Code which provided to consider, “the manner of distribution proposed, which may take into account the order of priority amongst creditors as laid down in sub-section (1) of section 53, including the priority and value of the security interest of a secured creditor”. India Resurgence Arc failed to consider that the provision uses the word ‘may’ which leaves it to the discretion and commercial wisdom of the Committee of Creditors (CoC) to consider if such priority should be given to any of the financial creditors. Thus, in the event of not being given any priority, a financial creditor cannot challenge it as a contravention of the law. To substantiate further, the resolution plan approved by CoC is valid in the eyes of law if requirements of Section 30 of the Code are fulfilled. The Supreme Court has also agreed with the same in the case of Committee of Creditors of Essar Steel India Limited v. Satish Kumar Gupta and Ors. (“Essar Steel”) wherein it observed that the amendment “only amplified the considerations for CoC” and was not meant to give any undue advantage to any one of the similarly situated class of creditors. Furthermore, the contention of the India Resurgence Arc for enforcement of entire security interest in its favour was also negated. The Court referred to Essar Steel, wherein it clarified that the amendment has been beneficial for operational and unsecured financial creditors who were now entitled to receive a minimum amount since prior to the amendment, the dissenting operational and unsecured financial creditors could be crammed down by the secured financial creditors. However, post-amendment, this is not possible since their interest is now secured. As regards the secured financial creditors, the proposition remains the same and a higher amount could contend only if it is not fair and equitable to such creditor. Therefore, a creditor can only claim a minimum amount that should be paid to it and cannot contend for a higher amount based on the security interest held by it. Addressing the contention of India Resurgence Arc to liquidate the corporate debtor,  the Court referred to the judgement of Jaypee Kensington Boulevard Apartments Welfare Association and Ors. v. NBCC (India) Ltd. and Ors. wherein the Supreme Court has held that a financial creditor can enforce the security interest but only to the extent which is receivable by it. The Court also clarified that enforcement to such an extent would satisfy its debts and would not contravene any of the provisions of the Code. It held that it was never intended by the legislature that a creditor having a security interest, be entitled to enforce the entire security interest but rather a proportionate part receivable by it. If any creditor is allowed to do the former, it will lead to inequality and be unjust to other secured creditors. Requirements of Law India Resurgence Arc preferred an appeal under Section 61(3) of the Code on the ground that “the approved resolution plan was in contravention of provisions of the Code”. It contended that the plan was not fair and equitable since it allowed for payment of nearly just one-sixth of the amount of the total security interest held by it. Explanation 1 to Section 30(2) of the Code states that the distribution should be fair and equitable to the creditors. The Court was of the view that the contention had no substance since all the secured creditors within that class had been provided with the same proportionate percentage share as India Resurgence Arc. Since it was provided with the same proportionate share as other creditors, it cannot raise an issue of unfair and inequitable treatment. If such an approach (as India Resurgence Arc) is adopted, then the creditors will be motivated to liquidate the company, as the appellant in the present case, which would defeat the objective of the Code. The same was also held in Essar Steel. In Swiss Ribbons Pvt. Ltd. v. Union of India, the Supreme Court very well emphasised that the objective of the Code is to revive the corporate debtor and

Priority in Enforcement of Security Interest by a Secured Creditor Read More »

The Case of “Amateur” Baseball Federation of India: Analysis Through Competition Lens

[By Pranav Tomar & Umang Chaturvedi]  The authors are students at the Rajiv Gandhi National University of Law, Patiala.  Introduction The commercialization of sports has strongly affected the landscape of sports federations in India. Now, these associations/federations act not only as regulators of domestic sports or facilitators to sportspersons but also add value to business houses. Recent trends prove that these Government-recognized federations are frequently found in conflict while fulfilling their duties due to the unparalleled power that they possess as entities. Hence, a check on such powers is of utmost importance, which can only be ensured through the law of the land. In consideration of such checks and balances, provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 (‘Act’) prove to be helpful in India. Recently, the Competition Commission of India (‘Commission’) in an information filed by the Confederation of Professional Baseball Softball Clubs (‘CPBSC’) held the Amateur Baseball Federation of India (‘ABFI’) in contravention of Section 4 of the Act (abuse of dominant position). In this piece, the authors analyse the acts of ABFI through the lens of precedents and the Indian competition law regime and will attempt to provide solutions to sports-related competition law violations. Facts of the Amateur Baseball Federation’s case CPBSC was a not-for-profit organization that worked for the development of baseball and softball privately, whereas ABFI was a National Sports Federation affiliated to the Sports Ministry that acted as the national regulator of baseball. ABFI was also affiliated with international baseball regulators and was officially entrusted with the duty of promoting the sport through various means. The matter stems from the act of CPBSC where it intended to organize an intra-club national Championship in February 2021 to provide a platform to young players. However, ABFI through its regulatory powers issued a letter dated 7th January 2021 that prohibited State affiliates from acknowledging private bodies and further threatened the interested players with disciplinary action if they participate in any unrecognized league. In fright, the registered clubs revoked their participation from the Championship which caused losses to organizers, i.e. CPBSC. Simultaneously, ABFI scheduled its flagship National Championship amidst the second wave of pandemic in late March 2021 and notified through a communication dated 1st March 2021. Eventually, the aforementioned communication turned out to be malafide considering that it was released after CPBSC finalized the dates of its private Championship and ABFI deliberately scheduled it on similar dates only to cause hindrance to CPBSC. ABFIs Championship was an event of utmost importance to all players as it gave them a chance to be considered for representing India in future. Hence, such acts caused chaos amongst the players and state bodies which forced them to choose ABFIs league only by not participating in another opportunity which was offered by CPBSC. ABFI case vis-à-vis precedents To tackle abuse of dominant position information, the foremost question the Commission faces is whether the organization is an enterprise? The commercial role of sports organizations forces them to comply with the definition of “enterprise” as provided under Section 2(h) of the Act. It was noted in Surinder Singh Barmi v. BCCI (‘Barmi’) that the definition of an enterprise is “wide enough to include any economic activity by an entity”. However, in ABFI’s case, the Commission went a step ahead and noted that even a non-commercial economic activity shall be subjected to the scrutiny of the Act. To do so, it used the “functional approach”, which has been relied upon in various Indian cases but primarily finds its mention in MOTOE v. Elliniko Dimosio. The approach suggests that every function shall be assessed separately as a federation may act as an enterprise when it is carrying one activity and not when carrying any other. In MOTOE, the Grand Chamber of the European Court of Justice stated that the economic activity having any connection with a sports-related act i.e. essential function does not restrict such entity from being scrutinized as an enterprise that in Indian parlance is defined under Section 2(h) of the Act. Further, the procedural set-up of the Act suggests that when the Commission adjudicates upon abuse of dominant position, a three-fold process is followed – Delineation of the relevant market in which enterprise exists Section 2(s) of the Act defines the “relevant market” for appropriate adjudication and determining the scope of the investigation. The relevant geographic market from Barmi to ABFI has always remained the same, in essence, India. It is the delineation of the product market that was presented through different approaches – (i) Consumer & multitude relationship approach (which states that federations have multiple functions to discharge with regards to other enterprises and consumers) in Dhanraj Pillay & Others v. M/s Hockey India (‘Pillay’); and (ii) the principle of substitutability (of sport & of services provided by one governing body) in Ministry of Youth Affairs and Sports v. Athletics Federation of India (‘AFI’). Based on the above-mentioned principles, the relevant market in ABFIs case was delineated as “market for organization of baseball leagues/events/ tournaments in India” because (i) no other sport can replace baseball; and (ii) no other regulatory body provides the necessary services. Establishing the dominance of enterprise within its relevant market The term “pyramid structure” finds utmost importance when determining the dominance of a sports organization. It refers to the organizational structure of sports entities which is modelled to fulfil governance loopholes. For instance, the Basketball Federation of India is the regulator and facilitator of basketball in India and has been recognized by another bigger regulator at the international level i.e. Fédération Internationale de Basketball. The same stands true with BCCI and ICC in the context of cricket. The pyramid structure has been noted in various cases in India like Barmi and Pillay. Although the pyramid is a monopolistic structure in itself, it ensures uniformity of sports globally. However, such structure makes these organizations the de facto authority coupled with factors like unilateral decisions, malafide bans on respective athletes, disapproval to local leagues, etc. further establishing their dominance before the

The Case of “Amateur” Baseball Federation of India: Analysis Through Competition Lens Read More »

Boardroom Gender Diversity: Are Mandatory Quotas Effective In India?

[By Swetha Somu]   The author is a student at Gujarat National Law University.  INTRODUCTION “Women Hold Up Half the Sky.”- Mao Zedong Analogous to this article is the proclamation made by Mao Zedong– to bring out women from domestic work to the professional field. Even today, if you walk inside a boardroom, it’s most likely that you’ll see more men like the Ambanis and Elon Musks than women like Kiran Mazumdar and Indra Nooyi. Through the lens of the law, the initial step was to empower women in corporate settings by imparting gender diversity in boardrooms. This article dives deep into the present scenarios in Indian companies and analyses the drawbacks and deficiencies of the mandatory quotas by discussing various other mandatory quotas imposed by countries around the world. The article seeks to bridge the gap in law so that the intention of the legislators, which is- diversity and inclusivity, is truly achieved. THE START: NORWEGIAN QUOTA The first-ever mandatory quota (40% for women in all listed companies) was legislated by the Scandinavian country- Norway, way back in the year 2006. The percentages jumped from 6% in 2002 to 40% in 2008 after its implementation. Although the percentage change pronounces the success of the law, various researchers have recorded negative effects and adverse changes in companies that had to comply with the quota. Shortly after the quota’s implementation, many companies had delisted from the stock exchange to avoid appointing a woman director. Some companies reduced their board size to easily comply with the quota and the women appointed were mostly for non-executive positions hence there was still no strong decision-making authority. Another research found that although the representation of women increased it didn’t mean many individual women in numbers rather the same woman being appointed in different boards. This is known as the “golden skirt” phenomenon. At the same time, researchers noted that more companies in Norway registered themselves in the UK and not their home country, hence pointing out that they were circumventing the regulations. Countries like France, Italy, and Germany followed Norway’s footsteps in implementing gender quotas in the boardroom. INDIA Since the patriarchal notions in the society are also seen to prevail inside the four walls of Indian boardrooms, the need for breaking this glass ceiling was acknowledged. A hindrance to women’s advancement is the existing gender stereotypes which diminish the scope of taking up high-positions in their professional lives. Hence to tackle this, the government introduced the Companies Act, 2013 in which under Section 149(1)(b) of Chapter XI makes it mandatory for the companies (listed companies, public companies with a minimum paid-up share capital of Rs.100 crores or minimum turnover of 300 crores) to appoint at least one woman director in their boardroom which failing to do so will attract penalties. This is known as a ‘hard quota’ where not following the quota will attract strict punishments unlike ‘soft quota’ which merely is a recommendation which if not followed, the company will only face warnings and negative reports. The second proviso to sub-section (1) Section 149 was inserted to increase the participation of women in key decision-making roles inching closer to the women empowerment goal that India wishes to achieve under the United Nation’s 5th Sustainable Development Goal of Gender equality by empowering women through strong enforcement of various policies and laws like this. After the implementation of the Companies Act, 2013 many companies started to comply with the mandatory quota as per the law. Subsequently, in 2015, the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) made all its top-500 NSE-listed companies compulsorily appoint at least one independent woman to their board by the year 2019, and the same for the top 1000 NSE-listed companies by the year 2020. According to the research article from the All India Management Association, out of the top NIFTY 500 companies in 2013, 303 of these firms did not have a single woman director on their board- which is roughly 60.6% of the companies that need to comply with the new quota immediately. Across these 303 firms, 82.8% had appointed one woman as one of their board of directors and 13.6% had appointed more than one woman in their boardroom going an extra mile! These huge percentages certainly seem to be promising and good going until we consider the scenario of efficiency after the appointment of the so-called women-in-power. Flaws and failures Though it was an overall success, there were some unpredicted drawbacks to the mandatory quota that India saw. Firstly, the imposed quota prompted ‘tokenism’ where companies appoint a woman director from their own family for the sake of complying with the law and to avoid the penalties. The NSE reported that 1667 of 1723 listed companies had fulfilled the mandatory quota but 425 of the complying companies appointed a woman from their family or promoters’ group. Illustration: Reliance Industries Limited has only one woman director (non-executive)- Mrs Nita Ambani, the CEO of the CEO, Mr Mukesh Ambani. Another company is JSW Steels, which has appointed Mrs Savitri Devi Jindal, the wife of the founder of Jindal Organization. The Raymond Group has appointed Mrs Nawaz Modi Singhania (non-executive director) who is the wife of the chairman. Secondly, there is a lack of skilled women willing to take up challenging positions, such as board members, making it hard for the companies to appoint and retain women at that position. This resulted in India being at the bottom of the table according to Egon Zehnder’s 2020 Global Board Diversity Tracker. Only 17% of the women held senior positions in companies and only 11% in leadership roles. Thirdly, the quota fails to meet what is known as the ‘critical mass’. With the minimum requirement of one woman on the board, the underrepresented gender does not have enough representation nor could make any substantial contribution to the boardroom discussions. A single woman on a boardroom meeting is likely to have a lower voice and is often neglected as it takes at least three

Boardroom Gender Diversity: Are Mandatory Quotas Effective In India? Read More »

The Whatsapp Privacy Policy & Abuse of Dominance

[By Tavashya Kumar] The author is a student at National Law University, Delhi. Introduction WhatsApp, one of the largest online messaging services in India and across the world, recently updated its privacy policy for users across the world which introduced changes to the manner in which a user’s data is stored and utilised when interacting with a business account on WhatsApp. It also seeks to enhance Whatsapp’s integration with Facebook, its parent company, by increasing the sharing of certain types of information such as account and transaction data. However, it has claimed that personal information such as private messages and videos will not be shared and that end-to-end encryption will prevail. The catch, however, lies in two facts- firstly, the privacy update is mandatory for users to accept. If they fail to agree to the terms within a stipulated deadline or refuse to do so, their accounts shall be deactivated. The second crucial factor is that WhatAapp has been discriminatory in the nature of its updates rolled out across the world. In fact, as pointed out by the Govt. of India in a letter to WhatAapp, it has rolled out a relatively less stringent update in Europe owing to the protections enshrined in the EU General Data Protection Regulations. The blog intends to examine this recent update in light of the provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 (Section 4 & Section 19) to ascertain whether this privacy update, and its mandatory and discriminatory nature, constitute an ‘abuse of dominant position’ on behalf of WhatsApp. Existence of Dominant Position According to Section 4 of the Act, abuse of dominance is established when an enterprise imposes unfair and discriminatory conditions on the purchase of goods and/or creates conditions that result in denial of market access. However, before determining whether the actions taken by a corporation amount to an abuse of its dominant position, it is first essential to establish that it enjoys a dominant position in the relevant market, failing which it cannot be scrutinised for abusive behaviour. This is because what may be commercially justified behaviour for non-dominant firms, may become exploitative or exclusionary in the case of dominant firms. There is a simple rationale for such a distinction- since non-dominant firms are bound by market forces, consumers can simply elect not to purchase their products and instead purchase from a competitor, which is not the case when the firm is in a dominant position. Accordingly, an enterprise is said to be dominant if it enjoys a position of strength in the market which enables it to operate independently of competitive forces in the market or affect its competitors or consumers in a manner which is beneficial for it. Section 19(4) of the Act provides an illustrative list of factors that must be considered by the CCI while establishing whether or not an enterprise is in a dominant position. This includes factors such as market share, size & resources of enterprise & its competitors, vertical integration & network effects, dependence of consumers on such enterprise etc. However, since dominant position refers to a position of strength enjoyed by an enterprise in the “relevant market”, assessment of dominance is to be preceded by delineation of the correct relevant market in which dominance is to be assessed. As laid down is subsections 6 & 7 of Section 19, this relevant market has two components- ‘relevant geographic market’ and ‘relevant product market’. In context of WhatsApp, the CCI has previously established that it is in a dominant position in the market in two noteworthy cases. In the case of Harshita Chawla v. Whatsapp & Facebook Inc., wherein the informant accused WhatsApp of violating Section 4 by using its dominance in the online messaging apps market to capture a different market (online payments), the CCI delineated the relevant market as ‘the market for over-the-top (OTT) messaging apps through smartphones in India’. Similarly, in Vinod Kumar Gupta (for ‘Fight for Transparency Society’) v.Whatsapp Inc., the CCI adopted a similar viewpoint, stating that its market is instant, internet based communication services through third-party communication apps on smartphones, which is different from text messaging services. Additionally, in both of the aforementioned cases, the CCI also held that WhatsApp was in a dominant position in this relevant market, on several grounds. Firstly, with regard to Market Share, the CCI observed that WhatsApp is the most downloaded and widely-used instant messaging app in India. It reached this conclusion by using publicly available information to ascertain that it had over 500 million active users, was installed on 96% of smartphones and was used by 64% of all Indian mobile users. It further observed that these figures were far ahead of its closest competitors such as Snapchat or, more recently, Telegram & Signal. Further, in both cases, it was held by the CCI that factors such as the network effect created by its vertical integration with Facebook and increased costs of switching from one platform to another create a dependence of consumers and constitute significant barriers to entry. Abuse of Dominance By WhatsApp Despite holding that WhatsApp is in a dominant position in both of the aforementioned cases, the CCI refused to hold it accountable for abuse of dominance in either scenario. Since the case of Harshita Chawla (supra) was in context of WhatsApp Pay, it did not raise privacy policies as an issue and hence is not relevant in the present context. However, the case of Vinod Kumar Gupta, which was filed subsequent to the takeover of Whatsapp by Facebook, is of immense relevance to the present situation. This is because it was filed in the context of a privacy update, akin to the present update, introduced by WhatsApp subsequent to the takeover. Through this update, users were forced to share certain personal information and account details with Facebook in order to continue availing services of Whatsapp. The informant alleged that these details were used by Facebook for purposes such as creating targeted advertisements. Further, it was alleged that the

The Whatsapp Privacy Policy & Abuse of Dominance Read More »

Scroll to Top